Imagine this: You could walk into a building and borrow, rent, or buy used books. We could call these buildings “libraries” or “used book stores”. Heck, while we’re at it, let’s also imagine people giving books that they’ve just finished to their friends.
If you look at the copyright law — 17 U.S.C. 106 — you may be surprised to see that the law explicitly says that these transactions cannot occur, at least without permission of the copyright holder. Really:
[T]he owner of copyright under this title has the exclusive rights to do and to authorize any of the following:
[. . .]
(3) to distribute copies or phonorecords of the copyrighted work to the public by sale or other transfer of ownership, or by rental, lease, or lending.
See? Illegal, all of it.
But of course, we know better. We know that libraries and used book stores exist, lawfully so at that, and (correctly) discount the idea that these institutions have cleared copyright with every single author and publisher whose work appears in their inventory. We also know that no one gets in trouble for passing a book to a friend.
That’s because of the First Sale Doctrine. Originally stemming from a 1908 Supreme Court case and codified at 17 USC 109 in 1976, the First Sale Doctrine, in a nutshell, says that the copyright holder only holds rights of distribution in order to put the product into the stream of commerce. Once the product is lawfully sold once, the right of distribution evaporates. So yes, go ahead and send me copies of books you think I should read.
But what about e-books?
Imagine, then, this: You could fire up your laptop or Amazon Kindle and borrow, rent, or buy a used book. Heck, while we’re at it, a friend could lend of give you a used copy of their book, too.
Right now? Unlawful. An exception to the First Sale Doctrine may render it irrelevant, and in any event, the digital transaction necessarily involves copying — thereby impinging on the copyright holder’s exclusive right at 17 USC 106 (1): “to reproduce the copyrighted work.”
Seems silly, but that’s the lay of the land.
Both John Battelle and Mike Shatzkin have posts today about e-books, and both touch on this. Shatzkin discusses best practices for e-book publishers to combat piracy while Battelle complains about features his Kindle lacks:
You can’t share a Kindle book with anyone else. That’s just nuts. The sharing of a book is perhaps one of the most intimate and important intellectual acts between humans, ever. I’m not stuck on whether or not that sharing is physical. I’m stuck on the inability to share. It’s a crime.
The juxtaposition shows the problem. The consumer (Battelle) demands the ability to share (“It’s a crime” that he can’t!) while the publisher (through the eyes of Shatzkin) is desperately trying to maintain control over the distribution of e-books, with the effect of controlling downstream distribution as well. These goals are irreconcilable, so something has to give.
Which brings me to the used book store in the cloud. Say an annual fee — $50? $100? — gave you the ability to rent a book directly to your Kindle or other device. The fee could be built into the price of a Kindle; as well as selling the current version for $259 without this service bundled, Amazon could offer it for $200 plus a $100 annual fee and multi-year contract, much like a cellular phone. Either way, one would still be able to purchase — permanently — a copy of an e-book whenever they see fit.
The books would actually live “in the cloud” — that is, on the publishers’ or distributors’ (Amazon’s? B&N’s?), and be pushed to your device as-needed, with some liberal allowances made for things like flying, etc., when wifi and cellular connectivity is lacking. Copying the file could be made difficult, especially if the service were limited to e-readers such as the Kindle. You could have a certain mumber of rented books on your device at a time, say three, but maybe fewer. And while your friend could not just give you a book he or she purchased, they could definitely recommend them to you via some sort of social network-like interface. But each of these digital copies would exist in a finite space, as determined by the publisher and policed by the distributor. Quite literally, we’d be applying the First Sale Doctrine to e-books as much as possible by re-introducing scarcity to (e-)books.
For Battelle, this would allow him, effectively, to share books with friends, so long as his friend was part of the renting ecosystem. As the annual fee would be easily incorporated into the Kindle’s price, this would be even more palatable. Further, I bet that one of his other gripes — that you can’t put the actual, physical book on your shelf — would be mitigated as the marginal cost to acquire the book would be offset in kind.
For Shatzkin and publishers, this would massively reduce the incentive to “pirate” e-books, especially among those consumers who would be likely to purchase books if otherwise available for a rental/browse/borrow discount. It would certainly cut into the number of sales of e-books, but because of the lack of permancy, not into the sale of paper-and-ink books. It probably is a net negative compared to the revenue stream provided by a world without e-books at all, but that universe is gone and not coming back.
The irony? While the publishing world looks toward saving the present structure, they’re doing so by ignoring the First Sale Doctrine — a common-sense point of law in both contexts. Adopting a First Sale Dotrine for e-books would be a huge step toward meeting everyone’s needs.
The copyright cartels will never allow an extension of the customary “dead tree” unlimited right-to-lend to e-books, as that way lies the ultimate collapse of artificial scarcity, something they live in mortal dread of. I discuss this issue at length in my debunking of the B&N Nook's lending feature: http://www.loper-os.org/?p=54
I think book publishers are a bit less afraid of the digital world than music labels, and that they would (in fact) allow for lending if it came with artificial scarcity. First, there's something special about the reading experience from dead tree books; second, they look great on a bookshelf (see Battelle's notes); and finally, music doesn't really exist in a tangible medium outside of distribution. That last point applies to books as well, but for some reason, feels different.
As for B&N's feature, you're couching it in terms which should be irrelevant — DRM, specifically. The cloud format renders DRM meaningless (See Mike's reply to http://www.idealog.com/blog/fighting-piracy-our…) while similarly maintaining scarcity.
> they would (in fact) allow for lending if it came with artificial scarcity
My point was that the level of scarcity we have grown used to from our experience with the “dead tree” world will not satisfy the publishers, as it could easily be transformed into a free-for-all. How many of the books on your shelves are not in your hands right this very instant? Well, if those were fully lendable e-books, someone in China could be reading them. And they would be right where they belong in ten seconds' time, should you decide to pick one up on a whim. The veil of scarcity wears thin, because e-books are able to teleport while paper ones are not.
> you're couching it in terms which should be irrelevant — DRM, specifically.
DRM is permanently relevant to any discussion of the e-book. Anything which wraps what would otherwise be an ordinary data file (cloud or not) and renders it artificially scarce is a form of DRM. A turd by any other name, etc. Overall, any technology which attempts to restrict what a user can do with an array of bits in his physical possession is an instance of DRM.
You could certainly lend your kindle to soneone else in order for them to read a book. And just like a real book you would be without it until it was returned. 🙂
However, what is probably needed is an Rhapsody for books.
Yeah 🙂 It'd be like letting someone live in my apartment (while I
went elsewhere) so they could read something on my bookshelf!
I think the Rhapsody angle is correct, in general if not specifically.
Here's what I wrote on Mike Shatzkin's blog. I think the issue is
that we need different solutions for different intents:
“It sounds like a “bundle of rights” problem. If I buy (“own”) a book,
I expect to be able to do things such as re-sell, loan, rent, gift it.
If I rent or borrow (“posses”) a book, I don't, but expect to be able
to do things like take it with me on a trip. If I am in your house and
flip through (“access”) a book, you being a mensch aside, I probably
can't just walk out the door with it.”
So if I buy a book or e-book, it should come with as many ownership
rights as possible. If I rent/borrow it, then the bundle I get is the
possession one. Etc. I recognize, of course, that having the ability
to copy the book and not the right is a bit of a muddle, especially as
the marginal cost to copy goes to zero, but I think that allowing the
other bundles of rights to exist in the commerce stream helps mitigate
that.
The reply I just left for the commentor below probably applies to a large degree to yours as well. I don't see any of this as an “or” question — we should be able to buy access without possession, possession without ownership, and I'm sure tons of other delineations which I can't think of. The reason for DRM — beyond the most aggressive of thieves — is to help make these bundles of rights meaningful, and more importantly and in the short term (I hope!) to make for an “easy” solution: an us versus them game and appeals to legal questions. But we both agree that the “easy” solution is not a solution at all.
> I don't see any of this as an “or” question
Whether I have absolute control over the fate of bits on a device which I bought and physically possess is, in fact, an either-or question. Either my computer is built to disobey my orders to benefit a hostile third party, or it is not: http://glyf.livejournal.com/46589.html
> But we both agree that the “easy” solution is not a solution at all
There are only two long-term solutions: a ban on true general-purpose computing (the logical conclusion of DRM efforts) or the complete abandonment of artificial scarcity. The latter could involve a clever social hack (i.e. the “ransom” model) or a reversion to the (historically dominant) situation of largely unpaid creativity.
Barnes & Nobel have apparently picked up on this concept, and their “Nook” allows e-book sharing. http://www.barnesandnoble.com/nook/support/?cds…
Re: and/or: Sure. But you can either put the file on your computer (DRM notwithstanding) or host it on the cloud. If you do the former, you own it; the latter, someone else does.
Eh, it's not really sharing, because you don't actually own the book.
It's just a reassignment of DRM nonsense and I think a previous
commenter is correct — it'll prove to be an “anti-feature”.
Barnes & Nobel have apparently picked up on this concept, and their “Nook” allows e-book sharing. http://www.barnesandnoble.com/nook/support/?cds…
> If you do the former, you own it; the latter, someone else does.
As soon as the contents of the file are in my bought-and-paid-for-with-no-fine-print-like-a-fork-or-a-knife video card's display buffer, I have taken ownership of them, Talmudic legal fictions notwithstanding. A copy is made in all cases, whether for my own viewing after I have been properly bled (Officially Blessed variant) or obtained from a warez site, with intent to distribute to the entire population of China (Officially Not Blessed.) The physical process which took place is the same.
Whoops. Didn't see the other comments when I posted.
The copyright cartels will never allow an extension of the customary “dead tree” unlimited right-to-lend to e-books, as that way lies the ultimate collapse of artificial scarcity, something they live in mortal dread of. I discuss this issue at length in my debunking of the B&N Nook's lending feature: http://www.loper-os.org/?p=54
I think book publishers are a bit less afraid of the digital world than music labels, and that they would (in fact) allow for lending if it came with artificial scarcity. First, there's something special about the reading experience from dead tree books; second, they look great on a bookshelf (see Battelle's notes); and finally, music doesn't really exist in a tangible medium outside of distribution. That last point applies to books as well, but for some reason, feels different.
As for B&N's feature, you're couching it in terms which should be irrelevant — DRM, specifically. The cloud format renders DRM meaningless (See Mike's reply to http://www.idealog.com/blog/fighting-piracy-our…) while similarly maintaining scarcity.
> they would (in fact) allow for lending if it came with artificial scarcity
My point was that the level of scarcity we have grown used to from our experience with the “dead tree” world will not satisfy the publishers, as it could easily be transformed into a free-for-all. How many of the books on your shelves are not in your hands right this very instant? Well, if those were fully lendable e-books, someone in China could be reading them. And they would be right where they belong in ten seconds' time, should you decide to pick one up on a whim. The veil of scarcity wears thin, because e-books are able to teleport while paper ones are not.
> you're couching it in terms which should be irrelevant — DRM, specifically.
DRM is permanently relevant to any discussion of the e-book. Anything which wraps what would otherwise be an ordinary data file (cloud or not) and renders it artificially scarce is a form of DRM. A turd by any other name, etc. Overall, any technology which attempts to restrict what a user can do with an array of bits in his physical possession is an instance of DRM. Anything which maintains scarcity is by definition DRM, because naked bits alone can never be scarce: http://ansuz.sooke.bc.ca/lawpoli/colour/2004061…
You could certainly lend your kindle to soneone else in order for them to read a book. And just like a real book you would be without it until it was returned. 🙂
However, what is probably needed is an Rhapsody for books.
Yeah 🙂 It'd be like letting someone live in my apartment (while I
went elsewhere) so they could read something on my bookshelf!
I think the Rhapsody angle is correct, in general if not specifically.
Here's what I wrote on Mike Shatzkin's blog. I think the issue is
that we need different solutions for different intents:
“It sounds like a “bundle of rights” problem. If I buy (“own”) a book,
I expect to be able to do things such as re-sell, loan, rent, gift it.
If I rent or borrow (“posses”) a book, I don't, but expect to be able
to do things like take it with me on a trip. If I am in your house and
flip through (“access”) a book, you being a mensch aside, I probably
can't just walk out the door with it.”
So if I buy a book or e-book, it should come with as many ownership
rights as possible. If I rent/borrow it, then the bundle I get is the
possession one. Etc. I recognize, of course, that having the ability
to copy the book and not the right is a bit of a muddle, especially as
the marginal cost to copy goes to zero, but I think that allowing the
other bundles of rights to exist in the commerce stream helps mitigate
that.
The reply I just left for the commentor below probably applies to a large degree to yours as well. I don't see any of this as an “or” question — we should be able to buy access without possession, possession without ownership, and I'm sure tons of other delineations which I can't think of. The reason for DRM — beyond the most aggressive of thieves — is to help make these bundles of rights meaningful, and more importantly and in the short term (I hope!) to make for an “easy” solution: an us versus them game and appeals to legal questions. But we both agree that the “easy” solution is not a solution at all.
> I don't see any of this as an “or” question
Whether I have absolute control over the fate of bits on a device which I bought and physically possess is, in fact, an either-or question. Either my computer is built to disobey my orders to benefit a hostile third party, or it is not: http://glyf.livejournal.com/46589.html
> But we both agree that the “easy” solution is not a solution at all
There are only two long-term solutions: a ban on true general-purpose computing (the logical conclusion of DRM efforts) or the complete abandonment of artificial scarcity. The latter could involve a clever social hack (i.e. the “ransom” model) or a reversion to the (historically dominant) situation of largely unpaid creativity.
Barnes & Nobel have apparently picked up on this concept, and their “Nook” allows e-book sharing. http://www.barnesandnoble.com/nook/support/?cds…
Re: and/or: Sure. But you can either put the file on your computer (DRM notwithstanding) or host it on the cloud. If you do the former, you own it; the latter, someone else does.
Eh, it's not really sharing, because you don't actually own the book.
It's just a reassignment of DRM nonsense and I think a previous
commenter is correct — it'll prove to be an “anti-feature”.
Barnes & Nobel have apparently picked up on this concept, and their “Nook” allows e-book sharing. http://www.barnesandnoble.com/nook/support/?cds…
> If you do the former, you own it; the latter, someone else does.
As soon as the contents of the file are in my bought-and-paid-for-with-no-fine-print-just-like-a-fork-or-a-knife video card's display buffer, I have taken ownership of them, Talmudic legal fictions notwithstanding. A copy is made in all cases, whether for my own viewing after I have been properly bled (Officially Blessed variant) or obtained from a warez site, with intent to distribute to the entire population of China (Officially Not Blessed.) The physical process which took place is the same.
No argument about the cloud. Once you store data on a hostile machine, others may read, delete, modify, etc. it. The only machine which contains data that can be meaningfully called “yours” is your own.
Whoops. Didn't see the other comments when I posted.
Pingback: What Does it Mean to “Buy” an E-book? « Dan Lewis